1. Introduction
Already in the 1960’s Tony Wrigley pointed out that the industrial revolution could be analyzed in
terms of changes in the way society was organizing its energy flows (Wrigley,
1962). Prior to the industrial revolution, energy flows were based on
photosynthesis, a system Wrigley labelled the organic economy. As the capacity
to produce energy in the form of foodstuffs, fodder and firewood through
photosynthesis was ultimately limited by the acreage available for forest and
agriculture, the potential for achieving economic growth was limited in the
organic economy, an argument that rests on the assumption that energy is
complementary to man-made capital. Coal did not experience the same limitations
on the size of the energy flows and therefore allowed economic growth. The
emergence of modern, high and sustained economic growth rates were therefore
closely associated with the succession from an organic to a mineral-based
economy. More recent empirical work has analysed energy transitions in several
countries based on quantitative estimates of the development of various forms
of primary energy such as firewood, coal and oil. The works of Tony Wrigley
(1988, 2010, 2016), Richard Wilkinson (1988), Peter Sieferle (2001), Kenneth
Pomeranz (2000) and even Bob Allen (2009) aims at understanding the industrial
revolution and they all, in different ways, recognize the role of energy in
this transformation. Another line of research has aimed at reconstructing
historical energy data in foremost physical units, elaborating measures such as
the energy intensity of GDP (Gales et al., 2007; Kander, Malanima & Warde, 2013; Lindmark & Minde, 2018).
The ambition of this article is to present an analysis of the Swedish
industrialization from an energy historical perspective, with the aim to
uncover dynamic relationships between economic and energy transformation. Our
main argument is that the Swedish industrialization process was shaped by the
co-evolution of organic and mineral systems and these dynamics, in turn, were
shaped by the industrialization process itself. We attempt to use a holistic
view, deliberately avoiding to focus on the energy system itself, while arguing
that the energy transition also interacted with institutional changes,
entrepreneurial activity and technological change that affected demand for
fuels and raw-materials through changing relative prices.
Early modern Sweden enjoyed vast per capita forest and hydropower resources
which, however, could not be fully realized due to relatively poor agricultural
conditions. Interestingly enough, the plentiful per capita forest and hydro
resources mirrored a low population density. Due to its fair supply of firewood
and hydropower, Sweden appears as a relatively blessed country during the
pre-industrialized era as far as energy resources are concerned. With the
exception of the southernmost parts of the country, forest was a dominant
feature of the landscape. Inland Norrland, a significant part of the country’s land area, was to an even higher degree dominated by woodlands. Yet, many of
these resources were largely inaccessible for economic exploitation of any
significant scale. The organic energy resources of a good part of the country’s area were therefore not assets in an economic sense. As we try to argue in the
article, this was a consequence of the organic energy system itself. The
paradox is that the organic energy system limited the access to organic
resources.
Map 1
Area of research
Around three quarters of the Swedish land area is found in the boreal coniferous
forest, or taiga. A short growing season meant that the supply of productive
agricultural land was limited in comparison to 3 European countries. The
exception was the southern parts of Sweden, with agricultural conditions more
similar to Denmark or Germany. We also notice evidence of agricultural
surpluses in the Stockholm Mälardal region from the 17th century (Myrdal, 1999). Generally, however, inadequate farming conditions,
mainly determined by the country’s northern location, explain the low population density compared to central
Europe. The flip side of the low population density was, however, a large stock
of non-agricultural assets in the form of forests and hydropower. Additionally,
Sweden was endowed with significant mineral resources, with known deposits of
iron and copper ores in the mid-central districts known as Bergslagen.
As the conditions for agriculture in these districts were not fully
satisfactory, but since parts of the surpluses in the Mälardal region could be used for supporting miners and iron workers, there was
enough manpower for the development of an iron and copper industry (Jonsson,
2001: 89-91) In short, the early modern iron industry benefited from a
favorable factor endowment of mineral resources, hydropower, decent
agricultural conditions and adjacent boreal forests for charcoaling. It was,
however, difficult or even nearly impossible to utilize the resources of
northern Sweden before the industrialization itself.
2. Northern Sweden and its factors of production
The fact that factor endowments frame the energy transition from an organic to a
mineral energy was evident in the case northern Sweden. In this part of the
country there were large areas of more or less unexploited forests, especially
old-grown spruce with high-quality, dense timber which was due to the slow rate
of growth in the harsh climate. When Carl von Linneus undertook his expedition
to Lapland in 1732, he noted the economic potential of the forests, but also
pointed out that the trees stood there, in vain and to no benefit. (Linnaeus, 1960). The timber did not have any commercial economic value.
Linnaeus argued that if only the right spirit was there to cultivate the
forest, there were enormous riches to be gained. While the continental powers
fought over overseas colonies, Sweden had a colony within its own borders. The
idea of an internal colonization was not at all new in the 1700s (Sörlin, 1988: 24). Sverker Sörlin points out that Olaus Magnus already in 1555 cited old authorities giving
voice to the same idea. Northern Sweden had several small coastal towns that
had been established in the Middle Ages, while the area was indeed populated
before the Swedish Crown had put the coast under its jurisdiction. For long,
historians have tried to understand who these first settler were, including
speculation over the true identity of the mysterious Kvaener as well as the
emergence of the Birkarlar in the 14th century (Harrisson, 2002: 741-50). The latter may have been a then new word for
the indigenous non-Sami population who earned their living in a combination of
agriculture, fishing, hunting and trade, and who, after the area was put under
the jurisdiction of the Swedish crown in the 14th century, also came to function as state officials and tax collectors. Northern
Sweden, not the least the interior parts, was also populated by the Sami
people, with an economy based on reindeer nomadism, fishing, hunting and trade.
The settlements in the interior were during the 1600s very small, obviously a
reflection of the harsh climate, most notably a short growing season with a
persistent risk of crop failure. Basically, proper farms were found along the
river valleys in the coastal area, while the inland favoured hunting. From a
biological perspective, northern Swedish agriculture was highly dependent on
dairy farming, since the short but intense growing season was relatively most
favorable for grass (Gadd, 2000). The Sami reindeer herding utilized
non-cultivated fodder, lichens, in areas were agriculture was practically
impossible. The forest was used for domestic building material and fire wood,
but not for commercial purposes of any important degree. An important factor
explaining why the forests were not used for commercial purposes was the low
population density and, therefore, an inadequate labor supply.
The existence of huge iron ore deposits in the northern parts of the country
were known from 16421 (Norberg, 1958). Regrettably, the majority of these deposits had a too high
phosphorous content to be utilized with contemporary technology. Sufficiently
large low-phosphorous deposits had, however, been discovered for advancing an
industrial exploitation, a project which faced at least two major challenges.
Firstly, the population in northern Lapland was even smaller than in other
parts of Norrland and, secondly, the forest supply was limited at best. This
meant that the ores of Norrland were inaccessible implying that the only
remaining solution was to transport iron ores to the ironworks that had been
established along the coast. The transport network, depending on rain deer
sledge transports during the winter was, however, not successful, due to low
economies of scale. It is furthermore important to recognize that the main
reason for allocating iron works along the Norrland coast was to counteract the
fuel shortages in the central Swedish iron districts. Due to the problems
related to transportation and extraction, the ores for the Norrland ironworks
were shipped from the Stockholm archipelago. The vision of a large-scale
colonization of inland Norrland, exploiting forest and mineral resources, was
however not possible until a sufficiently large population could be
established. Basically, this could not happen before the interior Norrland was
integrated in the growing national and international economy, something that
only happened decades after the Industrial Revolution. Before we attempt a more
holistic interpretation of the Swedish energy transition and industrialization,
it is, however, necessary to look more closely into how the hallmark technology
of the industrialization, the steam engine, diffused into Sweden, thereby
significantly linking the Swedish economy to the mineral energy system.
3. Sweden on Steam
The Dannemora mine steam engine project of 1728 exemplifies how factor
endowments, including not only energy but also technical know-how and real
capital, determined how technologies of the industrial revolution and the
mineral energy system could be applied in Sweden (Lindqvist, 1984). Already a
decade after Newcomen had assembled his first steam engines in England, the
powerful Swedish Royal Board of Mining decided to evaluate the technology. The
basic challenge that the Board wanted to address was, as in England, flooding
of the mines due to hydrological conditions. After the plans on evaluating a
steam engine had first surfaced in 1715, just three years after Newcomen’s first engine, a so called fire and air machine was built in the Dannemora iron ore mine in 1728, under the auspices of the
Swedish engineer Mårten Triewald. Unfortunately, it turned out that the machine consumed excessive
quantities of firewood. Since the wood had an alternative use as charcoal for
use in the nearby blast furnaces, foundries and forges, the opportunity cost
was high. This marks a striking difference to the British case, where the steam
engines were set up at the mouth of the coal pit where the fuel cost was close
to nothing. In Sweden, however, the costly fuel consumption meant that the
machine was not profitable, which in turn deterred the Royal Board of Mining
from resolving the remaining technical problems which, among other things,
included that it did not operate well under winter conditions. The production
factor missing at Dannemora was coal. Know-how, including engineering skills
and information on the British developments, was clearly present. The
institutional framework was also sufficiently well-functioning for encouraging
the investment in the first place but also to scrap the project when profits
were not realized2.
The first steps towards a transition to a mineral energy system in Sweden came
with the Watt steam engine and the British engineer Samuel Owen, a Leeds based
engineer who moved to Stockholm in 1804 on initiative from his Swedish business
contacts, who had previously bought British steam engines for two breweries,
one textile industry and one flour mill (Sundström, 2009). Bob Allen’s point that the technologies of the industrial revolution could not be diffused
until their designs had been sufficiently refined (Allen, 2009) therefore seems
to be justified also in the Swedish case. In Stockholm, Owen constructed his
first steam engines for industrial use, as well as small steamers such as the
Witch of Stockholm. Not without reason it is often considered that Owen played
an important role in the establishment of a modern engineering industry in
Sweden as several spin-offs such as Boliders (nowadays part of Volvo) and Atlas
Copco were started by his apprentices. Owen’s business operations may, from an organizational perspective, be seen as part
of the transition from the biological to the mineral-based energy system in
Sweden, and shows on the micro level how individual actors and entrepreneurs
played a role in the transition. In essence, Owen, and his Swedish business
partners, transferred critical know-how from Britain to Sweden. It is
furthermore likely, although it remains a future research issue to fully prove
the point, that the fuel demand derived from the increased used of steam
engines was a crucial driver behind the early diffusion of the mineral energy
system to Sweden.
4. The origins of the demand for coal
As railways directly contributed to an increased demand for coal, the national
railway project, with the first trunk line completed in 1856, was one of the
main drivers behind the Swedish energy transition. The reason why railways were
so important for propelling the transition was that railways did not run well
on firewood. The locomotives, originally of British or German designs, were
intended to run on coal. As a matter of fact, coal hold much better qualities
for steam engines as compared to biofuels such as wood or peat. This is
especially so concerning locomotives, with high demands on power and limited
size. Here lies some important, but often overlooked technical circumstances
which are important to consider. First, coal has a significantly higher energy
content in relation to its weight than biofuels. If volume is instead
considered, which is some respects is more important than weight, the
difference becomes even more striking. One cubic meter of wood is in energy
terms equivalent to approximately 0.17 tons of coal. As the density of coal is
about twice as that of wood, this means that one cubic meter of coal weighs
around two tons, which in energy terms corresponds to around 10 cubic meters of
wood. A steam locomotive such as model SJ Litt. B., a Swedish design from 1909,
had a fender with a coal storage capacity of 6 tons, corresponding to around 35
cubic meters of wood. Furthermore, as locomotives need to develop significant
amounts of power, there is a close relationship between locomotive power and
the boiler capacity, measured in tons of steam per hour. One important factor
affecting the boiler capacity is the rate at which the fuel can be burned,
which gives how much energy that can be transferred to the water in the boiler
per hour. Since the area available for burning fuel is limited in a locomotive,
attempting to run a locomotive on firewood reduces the boiler capacity and thus
the locomotive power by approximately 50%. Coal was also the preferred fuel for
stationary industrial steam engines, even though it is possible to keep up the
boiler capacity by simply constructing a large boiler and extending the
combustion area. Even in this case, a larger boiler would be needed if biofuels
were used. Adding to these disadvantages of biofuels, peat and even fire wood
also contain some amount of water, which means that energy is spent on drying
the fuel itself3.
FIGURE 1
Swedish coal imports by sector of destination, 1800-1913
Source: Lindmark and Olsson-Spjut (2018).
In quantitative terms, and as shown in Figure 1, Swedish coal consumption,
almost entirely based on imports, began to increase from 1840. Lindmark and
Olsson-Spjut have shown that the rise can largely be explained by the
increasing steam motive power in the industry, the development of steamship
tonnage, the recorded railway fuel consumption and the coal consumption in
gasworks (Lindmark & Olsson-Spjut, 2018).
Other sectors, including domestic heating and heating of other premises,
constituted a smaller, while not insignificant share of the coal consumption in
Sweden. Lindmark and Olsson-Spjut (2018) therefore suggested that the
increasing demand for coal during the second half of the 19th century was derived from the mechanization of the leading economic sectors
during the industrialization. Still, the Swedish energy transition was
characterized by a dynamic interaction between the organic energy system and
the mineral system, which created synergies between both systems. The expansion
of the saw mill industry along the Norrland coast initially utilized mechanical
hydropower. Steam power, a technology of the mineral system, grew in importance
from the 1850’s, especially because steam made it possible to locate the mills to more
favorable coastal locations. Still, the saw mill industry could utilize
sawdust, a biofuel of the organic energy system, as a main fuel for the steam
engines. Such synergies are distinguishing features of the Swedish energy
history during the 19th and well into the 20th century. Before we devote further attention to the manufacturing industry we
should look at the energy transition from the rural point of view.
5. Firewood in the domestic sector
During most of the 19th century, the Swedish primary energy consumption was dominated by fire wood for
domestic uses (Kander, 2002). Domestic heating and cooking technologies saw
significant improvements during this period, including the tile stoves and,
later, the iron stoves, which from the perspective of energy transitions begs
the questions whether these heating technologies saved on fire wood to such
extent that alternative uses of the forest resources, not the least as basic
raw material in the saw mill industry, could be realized. If so,
transformations within the organic energy system, may have played an important
role in the Swedish industrialization.
The historical sources on household firewood consumption are unfortunately
sparse and rather unreliable as far as the 19th century is concerned. We can therefore only make informed guesses about the
developments of fire wood consumption prior to the more reliable investigations
from the 1920s. What we know is that the bulk of the fuel consumption occurred
on the countryside and that the urban fuel consumption, also when counted per
capita, was significantly lower due to overcrowding and a more frequent use of
tile stoves. Urbanization therefore tended to reduce per capita energy
consumption. Both the iron stove and the tile stove were innovations with a
higher thermal efficiency than traditional fireplaces, but wether the new types
of stoves actually reduced per capita firewood consumption in rural areas is
not known with certainty. The dilemma is to what degree improved heating
efficiency was used for reduced firewood consumption or higher indoor
temperatures in combination with an increased number of heated rooms4. It is also uncertain how the growth of the landless rural working class in the
1800’s, living in smaller crofts rather than farms, affected the aggregated fuel
consumption. If one, as a counterfactual thought experiment, assumes that the
domestic per capita firewood consumption was the same in early the 19th century as it was in the 1920’s, one arrives at a consumption around 5 million cubic meters of fire wood in
1800. This roughly corresponds to the forest industry’s consumption of saw timber in the mid-1860s. If, on the other hand, the effects
of improved spacing heating technologies were strong, assuming that the per
capita consumption halved between 1800 and 1920, the household firewood
consumption would have been around 10 million cubic meters in the early 19th century, equivalent to the forest industry’s raw material consumption around 1890 (Lundgren, 1984). If so, the energy
savings within the household sector would literally have saved significant
amounts of firewood.
The forest industry was a key sector in the Swedish industrialization process
and the saw mill industry timber consumption rose from one million cubic meters
in 1840 to 11 million cubic meters in the 1890s (Lundgren, 1984: 223-25).
During the same period the total fire wood and charcoal consumption in other
manufacturing sectors probably increased from approximately 4.7 million cubic
meters to 6.5 million cubic meters of wood (Lindmark & Olsson-Spjut, 2018). The output growth, measured as the industrial value added
volume, increased sevenfold from 30 million to over 225 million 1913 SEK over
the same period (Krantz & Schön, 2007). This demonstrates a sizeable gain in terms of firewood efficiency
during the initial phase of Swedish industrialization, which was mainly driven
by a more efficient use of charcoal in the iron industry. Coal substituting for
firewood or charcoal was hardly important for the developments at the
aggregated level during the 19th century as the Swedish iron industry, by far the largest industrial consumer of
fuels, largely remained on charcoal until after the First World War.
The vast forest resources in interior northern Sweden were first utilized on
commercial scale from approximately 1850. This geographical expansion of the
forest industry, known as the timber frontier, originated in the Oslo area in
the 1700s. By the 1840’s, the frontier had reached the city of Sundsvall and twenty years later
northern Västerbotten to, finally, reach Norrbotten by the mid-1870’s (Bunte, Gaunitz & Borgegård, 1982: 135). An important driver was the demand for large, old grown timber
which became increasingly scarce as the saw mill operations expanded. The
timber frontier coincided both with a transformation of the agriculture in
interior Norrland and with the development of a distribution system of
foodstuffs from southern Sweden to the north and further inland. It is
important to recognize that the inland agriculture operated at the geographical
edge of farming. The famines of 1867, 1868 and 1869 had demonstrated how
sensitive the northern agriculture was to crop failures and how food transports
were disrupted when harbours froze over earlier than expected. When analyzing
the expansion of logging operations it is important to recognize that the
inland agriculture hardly produced any surpluses. Dan Bäcklund stated that the inland Norrbotten farms before 1870 could not even be
characterized as subsistence farming, if one, by referring to subsistence
farming, means a farm with some surplus production capacity that can be sold in
exchange for basic necessities (Bäcklund, 1988). Farming conditions were simply too poor, something that became
painstakingly clear during the frequent crop failures, such as the famine in
the late 1860s. Bäcklund therefore chose to label this type of agriculture subsistence small farming. Still, this form of agriculture in which grassland farming on outlying,
marginal land such as moors, was an essential support for the sparse
population. It was the expansion of the sawmill industry along the northern
Swedish coast that boosted demand for labor in the hinterland. For instance,
Nils-Gustav Lundgren has estimated that the 350,000 cubic meters annually
harvested in Jokkmokk area in Norrbotten around the turn of the century
required approximately 2,700 forestry workers (Lundgren, 1984). Owing to the
high demand for labor, there was also an increased element of wage labor. In
the 1880s, about 70% of smallholders depended on wage income, equivalent to
around 200 SEK per year, which in turn was equal to more than 100 days of
payments for an agricultural worker (Jörberg, 1972: 714). As forestry expanded and outfield farming was gradually
abandoned, it created a structural change within Norrland agriculture. Another
outcome was that more male labour in the forest required more women’s work in the agriculture (Bäcklund, 1988). In parallel, there were substantial investments in transport
networks. Streams were cleared from rocks and other obstructions to allow for
timber floating, while timber floatation on the lakes depended on steam tugs (Törnlund, 2002). The road network was expanded from the 1840s as state subsidies
were first introduced (Lassila, 1972: 151) and, as Bäcklund notes (1988: 47), the roads were absolutely essential for the expansion
of timber cutting from the 1870s. The railway reached Norrbotten in the 1890s
and along with coastal steam shipping from the 1840s and the construction of
inland roads, this provided the backbone of a distribution system partly
organized by forest companies, with the main purpose of providing fodder for
horses and food for the lumbers.
Northern Sweden held around 14% of the Swedish population in 1880, while the
output of grain and root vegetables, foremost potatoes, only accounted for 7%
of the country total (BiSOS, 1880c). The growing population in northern Sweden was therefore depending on
food transports from southern Sweden and from abroad. While the imports of
foreign grain to southern and central Sweden constituted less than 7% of the
production of grain in these parts of the country, the corresponding figure for
northern Sweden was close to 20%. Of the total Swedish meat imports in 1880,
almost 50% were destined for Norrland (BiSOS, 1880b). These transports were in turn mirroring the industrialization itself.
By 1880, the Swedish registered steamer tonnage belonging to staple towns and
private owners and intended for domestic trade was half the tonnage of sailing
ships (BiSOS, 1880a: tabs. 1, 2, 3). Norrland’s share of the sailing ship tonnage was around 7%, while Norrland’s share of steamer tonnage was 35%. This is well in line with the hypothesis
that modern technology was important for opening previously non-utilized,
organic forest resources. The railway reached southern Norrland by the late
1870’s and the north, connecting the Swedish trunk line to the Iron ore railway
between Luleå and Narvik in 1895. The role of the railways for facilitating the exploitation
of the bio-resources of the north is further exemplified by the so-called
Norrland Tariff, a railway transport subsidy in effect from 1895 to 1930 and
which mainly concerned grain freights from southern to northern Sweden
(Pettersson, 1999: 281). The tariff reflected both the southern Swedish farmers
need to find new markets, as the foreign competition had become harder during
the 1880’s, and the fact that Norrland was not self-sufficient in grain and
root-vegetables, while at the same time, both the forest industry and the
mining industry of the north needed more labour. Thomas Petterson (1999) points
out that prior to the railways, factory owners in Norrland were forced to store
foodstuffs in the autumn, before the harbors had not yet frozen over, a
solution that was both expensive and inconvenient.
The full utilization of the forest therefore depended on Sweden’s integration into the world economy and the use of coal based transportation
systems. In short, while sawn timber wasexported to the European markets, food
from southern Sweden and abroad such as American pork was distributed to the
hinterland. The role of coal was indirect as a fuel in both the transportation
networks and in the engineering industry that delivered machines to the saw
mills.
6. The charcoal consumption in the Iron Works
As previously pointed out, the charcoal consumption of the ironworks was
significant. Estimates suggest that 21 million hectoliters of charcoal was
consumed around the year 1800, equivalent to approximately 2.5 million cubic
meters of wood, which meant that the ironworks required a hinterland for the
supply of fuel and foodstuffs for the labor force. The localization pattern of
the ironworks was therefore rather diffused (Olsson, 2007). This was not only a
reflection of the area dependence of the organic energy system, but also due to
the difficulties in transporting charcoal long distances without the charcoal
shaking down into a powder. The production of charcoal was also strictly
regulated, which should be kept in mind when the role of relative prices in the
energy transformation is analyzed. To start with, there was a pre-emption obligation within the mining district (Olsson, 2007: 43). A Yeoman was obliged to first
offer the charcoal to the local iron work to a useful price. Only if they turned down the offer, it was allowed to sell charcoal outside
the mining district Bergslagen. This regulation was abolished in 1850. The
charcoal market outside Bergslagen was liberated in 1846, motivated by the
elimination of the Forging Ordinance the same year (Olsson, 2007). This means
that market prices for charcoal only came to existence from 1850.
The localization of ironworks, huts and hammers was administered by the crown,
through the Swedish Board of Mines, which set productions allowances and
conceded privileges for different parts of the iron production process. This
was both an expression of the mercantilist state and of resource management of
limited forest and hydropower assets (Olsson, 2007: 39-42). By the second half
of the 19th century, the iron industry was in a process of rationalization with extensive
closures. At the same time, however, iron production increased, implying a
concentration to larger units (Attman, 1986). The transformation pressure was
due in turn to the lower iron prices due to the increased supply of British
iron, which in turn ultimately depended on the increased production capacity
and high productivity achieved through coke-fired blast furnaces, in short
England’s transition to a mineral based energy system. The transformation of the organic
economy in Sweden could, theoretically, be the expected result if the price of
coal fell relative to fire wood and charcoal. It is, however, important to
realize that saw timber did not have an alternative use as firewood or charcoal
since the saw mill industry used larger timber dimensions as compared to the
dimensions used for fuels. First, large dimension timbers, often around 90
centimeters in diameter, were not as prone to sinking as smaller dimensions
when floated. Second, debarking a big log was more labor efficient per cubic
meter as compared to debarking a smaller log. In both cases this is due to the
geometrics of the cylinder; how surface area, which rises to the power of two,
is related to volume, which rises to the power of three. Thirdly, the saw dust
waste was relatively smaller when sawing larger logs. It is more convenient to
handle and split smaller logs, thus explaining why these dimensions were used
for charcoal and firewood. Since large and small timber were not close
substitutes, it is important to collect prices for both sawtimber and firewood.
The fuel and timber prices are shown in Figure 2.
FIGURE 2
Fuels and wood prices per MJ relative to coal. Sweden, 1866-1910
Sources: coal (Statens Järnvägar; BiSOS, 1866-1902; Kander, 2002: 1903-1910); charcoal (Olsson, 2007; based on Jörberg, 1972); wood pine (Jörberg, 1972); wood birch (Jörberg, 1972: 498ff, Skaraborg County); pulp wood (Ljungberg, 1990).
There is no reliable information on the development of coal prices in Sweden
from mid-1860, while a compilation coal prices for earlier dates have not been
made. The prices published as Swedish prices are, as shown by Fredrik Olsson
indeed series from the Danish historical national accounts, which in turn were
transformations of British export prices (Olsson 2007: 50-51). The prices from
1866 have been collected from the State Railways (Lindmark & Olsson-Spjut, 2018). Charcoal prices were approximately 5 to 15% lower per
Joule than coal prices until 1880, when charcoal became approximately 20% more
expensive than coal. This price relation lasted throughout the 1880’s and early 1890’s. This means that if coal and charcoal had been perfect substitutes, coal ought
to have replaced charcoal in the iron industry no later than 1880. Since that
was not the case, the two fuels cannot have been perfect substitutes. Also,
relative prices were relatively stable. A more pronounced relative price shift
did only occur during the period from 1894 and onwards. By the year 1900
charcoal was 50% more expensive than coal, and by 1910 charcoal was three times
as expensive. There were two reason for this. First, technical change had given
rise to an alternative use of spill wood and small timber dimensions as
pulpwood. When demand for small-sized timber increased, prices rose, which in
turn drew up the charcoal prices. Secondly, industrialization itself caused an
increased demand for labor, which caused rising wages also for the coalers.
Charcoal production was relatively labor intensive, which shifted the cost
structure especially for charcoal. The combination of the expansion of the pulp
and paper industry from especially the 1890s and more rapidly increasing wages
from the same decade explain the late switch from charcoal to coke in Swedish
blast furnaces, where the first coke fired furnace was started in 1905. In
short, it seems as if the major price-wise reason to switch to coke happened
when increased demand for small wood also made charcoal more expensive.
Simultaneously with the changeover to coke, there was also an increased
tendency of concentration in the iron industry into fewer but larger units.
This processes came to a climax during the economic crisis of the early 1920’s crisis, which virtually wiped out charcoal fired blast furnaces (Söderlund & Wretblad, 1957). The bottom-line is that coke enabled increased economies of
scale in the iron industry. The late transition to coke in Swedish iron
manufacturing may in turn be explained by the development of relative prices
for coal, firewood and labour. These changes were in turn partly the result of
the dynamics between the organic and mineral energy systems, as it was the
evolution of a wood based pulp and paper industry that propelled the final
stages of the transformation of the iron industry from charcoal to coke. First,
the pulp and paper industry’s demand for small timber resulted in rising prices for these dimensions which
altered the relative prices between coal and coke and, thereby, the cost
structure in the iron industry. At first only spruce was used for paper pulp
production, but as pine also became available for the pulp manufacturing
process, the competition over timber hardened between the paper pulp industry
and the charcoal manufacturing. Secondly, and as noticed previously, the
slender timber dimensions were inclined to sinking if floatation was attempted.
The forest industry’s cleansing of natural streams for more efficient timber floatation, investments
in coal consuming steamers, tugs and railways, made it possible to secure
supplies of raw materials to the pulp industry around the turn of the century.
Finally, while the raw material used in the pulp manufacturing process was
organic, the pulp and paper mills were highly depending on coal. In 1913, the
first year for which reliable data on the sectoral coal consumption in Sweden
exists, the pulp and paper industry accounted for around 30% of the
manufacturing industry’s total coal consumption. Coal fired steam engines were not the least used for
driving generators, providing electricity for machines. It is therefore not
surprising to learn that the pulp and paper industry’s share of the total installed engine power of the Swedish manufacturing
industry was also around 30% in 1913. The pulp and paper industry also changed
forestry itself as smaller timber dimensions became more valuable (Heckscher,
1941). First, thinning of the forests became profitable, thereby improving the
growth rate of large trees intended for saw timber. Secondly, a shorter
turn-around time meant that less capital was sunk in growing forests. This
improved the profitability of forest companies and probably facilitated the
emergence of sustainable forestry and practices that stood in sharp contrast to
the 19th century forest tycoons, often associated with illegal logging, land grabbing,
unethical business methods and deforestation (Gaunitz, 1990).
At this stage we are inclined to draw some tentative conclusions if we first can
explain why the use of coal increased dramatically, in presence of an absolute
price disadvantage in terms of cost per energy unit over firewood, while there
were no dramatic changes in relative prices between biofuels (firewood and
charcoal) and coal until the turn of the century. Price data shows that coal
was at all occasions more expensive than pine wood, while slightly less
expensive than birch wood.
The difference in price level can be explained if coal and charcoal were not
perfect substitutes in every respect. As previously argued this was clearly the
case concerning steam engines and especially so steam engines requiring a high
boiler capacity, such as locomotives. Thus, we can conclude that the increased
demand for coal was primarily derived from the demand for mechanical power
provided by steam engines in the manufacturing industry and transport sectors.
This explains why the coal consumption increased despite coal being more
expensive than pine firewood in terms of energy and despite the fact that coal
prices in comparison to biofuels remained fairly stable. In order to explain
why the relative prices were stable we need to conclude that coal and firewood
were close substitutes in low-end uses, such as residential heating. Coal had
an edge over firewood, but only in cities with houses equipped with central
heating and major coal imports for industrial uses and gas works (Lindmark & Andersson, 2010). Firewood therefore remained an important domestic fuel well
after the period studied here.
7. Hydropower
Hydropower was an important organic energy source which also was part of the
dynamics between the organic and mineral energy systems. This transformation
rested on two basic innovations, the turbine and alternating current
technologies. The first wave of saw mill expansion was based on mechanical
hydropower using water wheels. During the early stages of Swedish
industrialization, mechanical hydropower was essential for both the expanding
saw mill industry and had since long been of great strategical importance for
the iron industry. Gösta Eriksson even suggested that the demand for additional hydropower
contributed to the spatial diffusion of the iron industry during the 19th century (Eriksson, 1955). Indeed the total effect of mechanical hydropower in
the manufacturing industry and mining was larger than that of steam power as
late as 1900 (BiSOS, 1900a, 1900b). The official statistics reports approximately 250,000 HP in
mechanical hydropower and 174,000 HP in steam engines. Hydropower therefore
substituted for coal during the Swedish industrialization, even if it is
difficult to estimate the importance in terms of energy flows, as mechanical
hydropower usually did not admit continuous operation throughout the year. The
first turbines came to Sweden from Switzerland and France in the early 1840s’s and domestic production commenced a few years later with flour and saw mills
as the main customers (Spade, 2008: 35-6). From 1893 hydropower was again
transformed through the emergence of electrical engineering and alternating
current technologies. This time Sweden jumped on the bandwagon as one of the
leading nations. At the turn of the century, around 13% of the mechanical water
power was used for driving generators (BiSOS, 1900b). The considerable difference between industries regarding the use of
hydropowered generators is an indicator of the structural transformation of the
second industrial revolution. The new industries that represented the 20th century economy were often based on the use of electricity. More than 90% of the
mechanical hydropower in the chemical industry was used for driving generators.
And concerning electrical generators, the chemical industry was dominated by
chlorate and calcium carbide manufacturing. Chlorate was used in the match and
explosives industries, both emerging industries. Calcium carbide was used in
the manufacturing of acetylene gas, which in turn was used in carbide lamps, as
a welding gas and for purifying steel from sulfur. The transformation of
hydropower from mechanical to electrical hydropower was therefore also part of
a co-evolutionary process between the organic and mineral energy systems.
8. Conclusions
The Swedish industrialization was characterized by the co-evolution of the
organic and mineral energy systems. The saw mill industry was depending on the
establishment of transportation systems bringing in food stuffs for laborers
and loggers in the north and for transporting timber and sawn products to the
coast and foreign markets. Thus, the raw materials utilized were products of
the organic energy system, while the transport system was a mix of technologies
of the organic system, such as sailing ships and streaming rivers, and
technologies of the mineral system, including steamers, tugs and railways. The
diffusion of the mineral energy system was strongly associated with the
mechanization of the manufacturing industry and transports sectors where
firewood and coal were not as close substitutes as one could imagine. We
therefore propose that demand for coal was mainly derived from the demand for
steam powered machines while pure substitution effects, coal substituting for
firewood, were less important during the 19th century. The evolution of the wood based pulp and paper industry during the
late 19th century exemplifies the dynamics of the co-evolution of the organic and mineral
energy systems. As the pulp industry increased the demand for small timber,
prices rose for these dimensions which made firewood and charcoal more
expensive relative to other fuels. This contributed to the shift from charcoal
to coke in the iron industry but also changed the economic situation in
forestry as forest management became more profitable. Finally, also hydropower
was part of the change. Mechanical hydropower had been an important factor of
production with regard to the iron industry and, from the mid-19th century, the saw mill industry. With the emergence of electricity, hydropower
came to form the center of new clusters of industry and innovation for the 20th century. The Swedish example demonstrates how the dynamics of energy transitions
unfold in several dimensions, geographical, technological, economical,
entrepreneurial and institutional, and that these dimensions are often
interconnected. It is important to consider that aggregated analyses, focusing
on easily quantified dimensions such as the composition of energy carriers,
total energy growth and relative prices, may obscure how energy transformations
are linked to the general economic history of specific countries.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers for their valuable
comments and suggestions to improve the quality of the paper. The research was
supported by Stiftelsen Riksbankens Jubileumsfond through the project “The limits to growth in a sustainable society: Energy use and area requirements
in early modern Sweden” (Dnr P10-0701:1) and Jan Wallanders och Tom Hedelius Stiftelse samt Tore
Browaldhs Stiftelse “Engines for sustainability. Horsepower prices, capital sub- stitution and energy
transitions in the long run”.
REFERENCES
Allen, R. C. (2009). The British Industrial Revolution in Global Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Attman, A. (1986). Svenskt järn och stål 1800-1914. Stockholm: Jernkontoret. (Jernkontorets bergshistoriska skriftserie, 21).
Bäcklund, D. (1988). I industrisamhällets utkant: Småbrukens omvandling i Lappmarken 1870-1970. Doctoral dissertation. Umeå: Umeå Universitet.
BiSOS (1866-1902). Statens järnvägar (L). Stockholm: Statistics Sweden.
Bunte, R., Gaunitz, S. & Borgegård, L. E. (1982). Vindeln: En norrländsk kommuns ekonomiska utveckling 1800-1980: En analys av bondesamhällets ekonomiska utveckling, anpassning och förvandling under 200 år. Lund: Degerfors.
Eriksson, G. A. (1955). Bruksdöden i Bergslagen efter 1850: Med särskild hänsyn till företag i Kolbäcksåns dalgång. Stockholm: Jernkontoret. (Jernkontorets Bergshistoriska Skriftserie, 15).
Gadd, C. J. (2000). Det svenska jordbrukets historia. 3: Den agrara revolutionen 1700-1870. Stockholm: Natur och Kultur.
Gales, B., Kander, A., Malanima, P. & Rubio, M. (2007). North versus South: Energy Transition and Energy Intensity in Europe
over 200 Years. European Review of Economic History, 11(2), 219-253.
Gaunitz, S. (1980). Baggböleriet-om konsten att avverka norrlandsskogarna utan att bryta för mycket mot lagen. Västerbotten, (1), 2-14.
Harrison, D. (2002). Jarlens sekel: En berättelse om 1200-talets Sverige. Stockholm: Ordfront.
Heckscher, E. F. (1941). Svenskt arbete och liv: Från medeltiden till nutid. Stockholm: Bonnier.
Jonsson, K. (2001). Järnhanteringen i norra Västergötland: Arkeologiska undersökningar i Essunga, Främmestad, Istrum, Ledsjö, Lerdala, Vättlösa och Älgerås socknar. Stockholm: Jernkontoret. (Jernkontorets Bergshistoriska Utskott, 71).
Jörberg, L. (1972). A History of Prices in Sweden 1732-1914. 1: Sources, Methods, Tables. Lund: Gleerup.
Kander, A. (2002). Economic Growth, Energy Consumption and CO2 Emissions in Sweden 1800-2000. Doctoral dissertation. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell. (Lund Studies in Economic History, 19).
Kander, A., Malanima, P. & Warde, P. (2013). Power to the People: Energy in Europe over the Last Five Centuries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Krantz, O. & Schön, L. (2007). Swedish Historical National Accounts 1800-2000. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell. (Lund Studies in Economic History, 41).
Lassila, M. (1972). Vägarna inom Västerbottens län: Kommunikationernas utveckling mot bakgrund av befolkning och näringsliv. Umeå: Umeå Universitet.
Lindmark, M. & Andersson, L. F. (2010). Household Firewood Consumption in Sweden during the Nineteenth Century. Journal of Northern Studies, (2), 55-78.
Lindmark, M. & Olsson-Spjut, F. (2018). From Organic to Fossil and In-Between: New Estimates of Energy
Consumption in the Swedish Manufacturing Industry during 1800-1913. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 66 (1), 18-33.
Lindmark, M. & Minde, K. B. (2018) Et energiregnskap for Fastlands-Norge 1835-2012/Energy Consumption in
the Norwegian Mainland Economy 1835-2012. Heimen, 55 (2), 157-177.
Lindqvist, S. (1984). Technology on Trial: The Introduction of Steam Power Technology into Sweden,
1715-1736. Uppsala/Stockholm: Uppsala Universitet/Alqvist & Wiksell. (Uppsala studies in history of science, 1).
Linnaeus, C. (1960 [1732]). Carl von Linnés lappländska resa: Caroli Linnæi Iter Lapponicum. Stockholm: Natur och Kultur.
Ljungberg, J. (1990). Priser och marknadskrafter i Sverige 1885-1969: En prishistorisk studie. Doctoral thesis. Lund: Ekonomisk-historiska fören. (Skrifter utgivna av Ekonomisk-historiska föreningen, 64).
Lundgren, N. G. (1984). Skog för export: Skogsarbete, teknik och försörjning i Lule älvdal 1870-1970. Doctoral dissertation. Umeå: Umeå Universitet. (Umeå studies in Economic History, 6).
Myrdal, J. (Ed.) (1999). Det svenska jordbrukets historia. 2: Jordbruket under feodalismen: 1000-1700. Stockholm: Natur och kultur.
Norberg, P. (1958). Forna tiders järnbruk i Norr- och Västerbotten. Stockholm: Almqvist & Wiksell.
Olsson, F. (2007). Järnhanteringens dynamik: Produktion, lokalisering och agglomerationer i
Bergslagen och Mellansverige 1368-1910. Doctoral dissertation. Umeå: Umeå Universitet. (Umeå studies in Economic History, 35).
Pettersson, T. (1999). Institutional Rigidity and Economic Change: A Comparison between
Swedish Transport Subsidies. In L. Andersson-Skog & O. Krantz (Eds.), Institutions in the Transport and Communications Industries: State and Private
Actors in the Making of Institutional Patterns, 1850-1999 (pp. 199-215). Canton: Science History Publications.
Pomeranz, K. (2000). The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Sieferle, R. P. (2001). The Subterranean Forest: Energy Systems and the Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: The White Horse Press,
Söderlund, E. & Wretblad, P. E. (1957). Fagerstabrukens historia. 3: Nittonhundratalet. Uppsala: Almqvist & Wiksell.
Sörlin, S. (1988). Framtidslandet: Debatten om Norrland och naturresurserna under det
industriella genombrottet. Stockholm: Carlssons.
Spade, B. (2008). En historia om kraftmaskiner. Stockholm: Riksantikvarieämbetet.
Sundström, A. (2009). Samuel Owen: Teknik- och ångbåtspionjär. In Dædalus: Tekniska museets årsbok. Vol. 77. Stockholm: Tekniska museet.
Sverige Kommerskollegium (1880a). Bidrag till Sveriges officiella statistik (BiSOS). E) Inrikes och sjöfart handel. Stockholm: L. J. Hjerta.
Sverige Kommerskollegium (1880b). Bidrag till Sveriges officiella statistik (BiSOS). F) Utrikes handel och sjöfart. Stockholm: L. J. Hjerta.
Sverige Kommerskollegium (1880c). Bidrag till Sveriges officiella statistik (BiSOS). N) Jordbruk och boskapsskötsel. Stockholm: L. J. Hjerta.
Sverige Kommerskollegium (1900a). Bidrag till Sveriges officiella statistik (BiSOS). C) Bergshandteringen. Stockholm: L. J. Hjerta.
Sverige Kommerskollegium (1900b). Bidrag till Sveriges officiella statistik (BiSOS). D) Fabriker och handtverk. Stockholm: L. J. Hjerta.
Törnlund, E. (2002). “Flottningen dör aldrig”: Bäckflottningens avveckling efter Ume- och Vindelälven 1945-70. Doctoral dissertation. Umeå: Umeå Universitet. (Studies in Economic History, 27).
Wilkinson, R. G. (1988). The English Industrial Revolution. In D. Worster (Ed.), The Ends of the Earth: Perspectives on Modern Environmental History. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wrigley, E. A. (1962). The Supply of Raw Materials in the Industrial Revolution. The Economic History Review, 15 (1), 1-16.
Wrigley, E. A. (1988). Continuity, Chance and Change: The Character of the Industrial Revolution in
England. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wrigley, E. A. (2010). Energy and the English Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Wrigley, E. A. (2016). The Path to Sustained Growth: England’s Transition from an Organic Economy to an Industrial Revolution. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
NOTAS A PIE DE PÁGINA / FOOTNOTES